Michael
Blankenship
October
9, 2000
Eco-Criticism
Cronon,
William. Nature’s Metropolis:
Chicago and the Great West. New
York: W.W. Norton and Company, 1991.
William
Cronon was fascinated by Chicago for the same reasons that all people are drawn
to cities: curiosity. For those of us
not from a city, the urban environment seems simultaneously beautiful,
frightening and dangerous, exciting, and disgusting. Cronon begins Nature’s Metropolis by recalling his
childhood memories of passing through the city and uses these memories as the
launching point to explore how 19th Century Chicago developed from a
trading camp in the 1800s into the metropolis that was revealed at the 1893
World’s Columbian Exposition.
For
the purposes of our class, Nature’s Metropolis doesn’t seem to have a
direct link to Eco-criticism. In fact,
despite having the façade of a history text, the book is much more of an
example of applied economics than any sort of history or literary theory
text. What is interesting to those with
an Eco-critical eye is the way Cronon links the evolution of Chicago to the
frontier and rural areas surrounding the city by exploring the flow of
resources into the city. In other
words, the city is not an island amidst a sea of savage wilderness; it depended
on (and still depends upon) the resources that surrounded it to thrive (see
explanation of von Thunen’s theory below).
Although much of Chicago’s
history is revealed through his exploration, many events that would seem
important are deleted. People are
downplayed and the town as a whole highlighted. You leave the book having no idea what a 19th Century
citizen of Chicago was like. What you
do take is a better understanding of how capitalism makes the world (especially
The United States) go around.
Cronon’s
idea for Nature’s Metropolis stems from his disagreement with a theory
proposed at the World’s Columbian Exposition, a world’s fair that took place in
Chicago in 1893 to celebrate the 400th anniversary of Columbus’
discovery of the Americas. When asked
to explain the American westward domination, Frederick Jackson Turner proposed
his theory. Combining Manifest Destiny
and Social Darwinism, Turner believed that this domination was the result of
the “social evolution” of Europeans and Americans who sought to bring order,
reason, and ultimately productivity out of the primitive savagery of “the
frontier.” In other words, white man’s
evolutionary superiority over Native Americans and their willingness for order
led them to conquer the West. This
order eventually manifested itself in a city like Chicago, the ultimate example
of order within Nature. By taking
advantage of naturally occurring geographical/natural potential, western man
prospered. Modern thinking has done
little to challenge this idea. Cronon,
however, believes differently. Through
an enormous amount of research (which is footnoted and explained in a 115-page
appendix), Cronon demonstrated that capital was the reason the city was created
and still exists today.
The location of Chicago had
long been recognized as a geographically valuable place. Trading posts were located there, Native
Americans lived along the shores of Lake Michigan, and its close proximity to
the sluggish, shallow Illinois River made travel by small boat easy. As westward expansion became more prevalent,
more national views came into play. No
longer was Chicago just a good place to live; it was a good place for a city.
Thinking
on this larger scale, it became evident that there would be a great advantage
to developing the Chicago area. This is
where “the boosters” come into the picture.
Land speculators hoping to get rich quick saw the value the area and the
potential it had to evolve. Its
location between Lake Michigan and the Illinois River (which flowed into the
Mississippi and eventually the Gulf of Mexico) made it a perfect canal
candidate. A canal would create an
interior route from the North Atlantic to the Gulf of Mexico. The prairie that surrounded the city begged
to be farmed. Mining operations could
be established, and timber abounded north of Chicago. Reading Turner’s theory backwards, the boosters hoped to create
the city that was destined to evolve anyway due to geography. They hoped to buy the land while they could
and get rich off of it as the city finally caught up to its potential.
As
the Native Americans were removed through shifty government purchases, one of
the biggest land speculation movements in U.S. history began. Lots of swampy prairie land sold for
outrageous prices. The land often
changed hands in a matter of days only to be sold the next week for even more
money. The interesting thing was that
the actual city didn’t exist. The land
on which to build it was sold, but there was no business to generate
revenue. The only items sold in the
city were lots.
Eventually, it became evident that the city
wasn’t growing as it was destined to grow…at least not as quickly as investors
would like. The real drive behind the city’s evolution came not from some
natural evolution but from these worried investors. So much capital was tied up in the would-be city that something
had to be done. The canal, proposed and
eventually built, proved to be just short of a disaster as sand constantly
clogged the shallow water that ran through it.
The railroad eventually came into the picture (sponsored by the
government) and soon all but eliminated travel by water. In fact, the railroad became the secret to
solidifying the mirage of Chicago.
Focusing
on economics, Cronon explains the relationship between a city and the
countryside that surrounds it. A city
can’t exist without having a purpose.
Commercially successful rural areas can’t exist without a market for
their goods. Thus, a symbiotic
relationship exists. Capital, in the
form of lumber, livestock, grain, and ore, flows into the city where it is
turned to liquid capital in the form of money.
In other words, cities act as funnels and markets for non-liquid
capital.
Citing support for this
idea, Cronon quotes Johann Heinrich von Thunen’s 1826 book, The Isolated
State. Thunen theorizes that an
isolated city-state will structurally evolve due to economic factors. The city will be at the center with
agricultural, mining, and lumber industries surrounding the city based on
monetary factors. The more costly the
transportation cost of the item, the closer that item will be to the city. The city itself acts as a center of commerce
rather than the center of the Universe.
It is not a self-sufficient region but is dependent upon the resources
surrounding it.
Under this theory, Chicago
shouldn’t have grown as quickly as it did.
The surrounding areas could not have supported the rapid growth that occurred
there. What changed Thunen’s situation
were the railroad and telegraph. These
items basically shrunk the world allowing Chicago to link to the East. Capital continued to flow in from
everywhere, and Chicago became a boomtown.
The railroad not only made
travel into Chicago easier for outlying farmers; it encouraged farmers from
great distances away to trade their goods in Chicago. To understand Cronon’s slant, consider this demonstration of his
theory. The ideas of fixed and variable
costs became factors to the railroad industry.
Since they were in charge of loading and unloading grain, for example,
on and off of the train, this cost was fixed.
It costs the same amount to load and unload 5 tons of grain whether the
grain moved 5 feet or 500 miles. Other
fixed costs included wage employees and warm up fuel costs for the steam
locomotives. Where the railroad could
make up the difference was in charging distance rates. Since the distance from any given Farm X to
Chicago was always different, this represented a variable cost. The further the farm was from Chicago, the
cheaper the rate per mile traveled since only variable costs change. Likewise, shorter trips were often more
expensive (per mile) than longer trips.
This odd bit of economic logic encouraged farms far from Chicago to ship
their product through the bustling city further encouraging development.
As the railroad became more
dominant, the world effectively shrank because of the technological
advance. Investors poured money into
the city, and the self-fulfilling prophecy of Chicago actually occurred. The drive was totally fueled by economics
and capitalism. Without the revenue,
the swamp that was old Chicago would most likely still be a swamp.
The structure of this book
is interesting. After a brief
introduction, Cronon looks at the primary economic factors one at a time
tracing them from their origins to the end of the 19th century. This nonlinear organization often leaves the
reader wondering exactly when a given event occurred. However, like I said, Nature’s Metropolis
only pretends to be a history book while the true topic is applied
economics. Anyone with an interest in
agriculture, the lumber industry, or the meat industry in Chicago during this
time period would find this text interesting.
However, aside from Cronon’s reliance on von Thusen’s theory, this text
has little Eco-critical appeal.